February 17, 2014
Economics, Emissions, Grid

Where Wind Studies Go Wrong: Cullen in AEJ

Hawkins, Kent

Part I

The nature of the short-term operation of an electricity system is more like that of a machine than a market.

A paper published by Joseph Cullen in the American Economic Journal: Economic Policy (November 2013), “Measuring the Environmental Benefits of Wind-Generated Electricity” [1] [1] [2] is important in two regards. First, using Texas data, it shows that even with notable emissions savings attributed to wind, the highly subsidized cost of wind is exceeded only by high estimates of the social costs of pollution.

Secondly and perhaps more importantly, his paper provides an opportunity to illustrate where wind-performance analyses fall short. This is the subject of this two-part post today and tomorrow, and is independent of the issue of carbon dioxide social benefits versus social costs.

Professor Cullen first determines how much electricity production of other generator types is offset by the presence of wind plants in the grid using a reduced form econometric model based on “observed behavior and current market conditions.” The time frames for production are 15 minute intervals and two hour ahead forecasting by market participants. The market-oriented approach is exemplified by the following quote:

When low marginal cost wind-generated electricity enters the grid, higher marginal cost fossil fuel generators will reduce their output. [emphasis added]

This assumption that the suppliers of generation resources make these decisions is questionable because the nature of the short term operation of an electricity system is more like that of a machine than a market. The electricity system has been described as, “the largest and most complex machine ever made.” [3] Usually the production offset by wind is that which is most easily and quickly varied by the system operator regardless of fuel source or cost. Further, depending on the generation fleet online profile at the time, this can be other emissions free generation, such as hydro or even in some cases nuclear, which admittedly is not easily varied.

This is not to say there is not a wholesale electricity market, but that critical short term electricity system operational considerations are less dependent on decisions by the market participants and more dependent on the system operator matching supply and demand in real time using available online dispatchable generation resources.

So, although the operation of the electricity system is intended to provide the lowest wholesale cost from available choices, the overall reliability of the system is the paramount consideration. Other factors impacting operational decisions include: (1) government mandates to accept wind plant production whenever it occurs; (2) the profile of generation plants in use at the time (this typically varies considerably throughout the 24 hour day, and can be a limited subset, particularly at night); and (3) as already indicated, which of the available online generation plants can most easily be varied to meet the erratic output of wind plants. The Cullen analysis does not take into account the over-riding reliability consideration, as explained at the bottom of page 111.

Finally, the econometric approach cannot comment on wind-induced reliability, or congestion issues that engineering approaches are geared to address.

Having determined the production offsets, the paper suggests that “it is straight forward to calculate emissions offsets by wind.” The emphasis is added because the “straight forward” claim is very questionable. So this review will put both sets of results to the test, and they will be found wanting.

Can opposition to wind plant implementations be encouraged by the results nonetheless? I suggest not without considerable caution for a number of reasons:

Part I of this series addresses the following in more detail:

Analysis Approach

A summary of Cullen’s approach is:

Utilizing information on production decisions [by market participants] in 15-minute intervals on the Texas electricity grid, I estimate the response of each generator to exogenous changes in wind power. Realizing that wind power production is not completely random, I control for factors that may drive the incentives for electricity production, which may also be correlated with wind power production. The resulting quasi-experimental residual variation is then used to identify a substitution coefficient for each generator on the grid. Importantly, I show that failing to control for impact that wind has on the dynamic process of electricity production overestimates the production offsets. These production offsets then translate directly into emission offsets using generator emission rates. [emphasis added]

This approach may work if all the factors in determining production and emissions offsets are accounted for, which I suggest is not an easy task, and has not been convincingly and completely done by anyone. Cullen does include a number of factors, but are important ones missed?

One way to test for this is to provide two finely-grained (5 minute intervals or less) time series plots for wind production versus both fossil fuel production offsets and emissions offsets claimed for wind. If these plots clearly show, in timing and relative size, that a very close relationship (or mirror image in the case of negative correlation), then there is merit to the approach. In the absence of a demonstration of this strong cause and effect relationship, the degree of mismatch is an indication of the impact of other factors not modelled.

In the case of the Kaffine, McBee and Lieskovsky study referred to by Cullen, because it employed the same approach “using different data sources”, when such time series plots were provided, there was little indication of a cause and effect relationship between wind production and the residual emissions claimed as a consequence of wind presence.

As a quick test of the possible causal links between wind and fossil fuel electricity production I looked to a chart I had previously prepared for Texas using EIA data.[2] [4] It includes the period analyzed in Cullen’s paper, that is 2005-2007, and is shown in Figure 1. This chart focuses on the changes in electricity production on a yearly basis for fossil fuel plants, wind plants and net imports as an indicator of plausible cause and effect.

Figure 1 shows that in five of the eight years the annual change in wind production is in the same direction (both up or down) as that for fossil fuel, which suggests that wind is not the major factor in offsetting fossil fuel generation. However, for five of these years the change in net imports is in the opposite direction as changes in fossil fuel production. Note the relative sizes as well. This suggests that imports are more likely a factor than wind in offsetting fossil fuel electricity production.

Do not be confused by the use of the term net imports, in the context of a net exporter for the time period in Cullen’s analysis. Net imports are used here because imports are an additive generation source and are thus shown as positive in the chart. When net import changes are positive, year over year, this means there was an increase in imports relative to exports.

This test may not be conclusive, but it reinforces that further verification as described above would be appropriate.

In the absence of such corroboration, the results remain suspect because the sophistication of the approach is not a guarantee of accuracy. See more comment under the Robustness Claim (below) and Interstate Trade in Electricity sections in Part II.

There is interesting information bearing on the impact of cycling fossil fuel plants, whether for just “normal” frequency regulation (load variation only) or the additional requirement of balancing wind. [3] [5] On a short term basis, such as minutes (or less), both have the same type of system impact. This is referred to in a KEMA [4] [6] report, “Emissions Comparison for a 20 MW Flywheel-based Frequency Regulation Power Plant” [7] in which a reference is made to another KEMA report on the impact of such cycling on the fuel consumption and hence emissions of fossil fuel plants. Attempts to get a copy of the referenced report have not been successful, but Dr. Kees lePair, in the Netherlands, claims to have had access to it and describes its findings in his paper “Wind turbines increase fossil fuel consumption & CO2 emission” [8] as follows:

Recently we received some information concerning a fuel flow recording of a coal fired generator during cycling. The generator running stationary for some time at 100% of its optimal capacity reduced its output to 80% and up again to 100%. The whole cycle took place in one hour. The total fuel consumption during that period was 1,2% more than it would have been had the machine continued running at 100%. It was suggested that for a CCGT this outcome should have been 1%.

Given the combined effect of: (1) the more frequent cycling of fossil fuel plants than KEMA observed, whether normal frequency regulation operations or balancing wind plants, and (2) an overall reduced electricity output, and therefore less efficient operation due to periods of part loading in the fossil fuel plants as a result, it is difficult to escape the expectation of very little emissions savings at best over a normal steady operation of the fossil fuel plants meeting the demand alone. In other words, wind presence likely increases emissions overall.

In the first paragraph in the “Robustness” section of Cullen’s paper he expresses some concern about using averages of emission rates and acknowledges emissions effects missed, but counters this with the claim that as the number of fossil fuel plants supporting this cycling requirement increases, the changed output of each would be eased thus reducing the fuel and emissions impacts. This misses the important consideration that the frequency of such cycling is at least, if not more than, as important as the extent of the changes required. Further, grid topology could also restrict wind’s impact to subsets of fossil fuel plants.

Robustness Claim

In the “Robustness” section the paper looks to the Katzenstein and Apt analysis “Air Emissions Due to Wind and Solar Power” [9] for confirmation of results. Most readers appear to miss the many caveats that Katzenstein and Apt correctly identify. For example:

As discussed in the Supporting Information [10], the emission and heat rate data we obtained for the gas turbines did not cover all combinations of power and ramp rate. We therefore further constrain the model to operate only in regions of the power-ramp rate space for which we have data.” [emphasis and link added]

and,

and caution that we have made no attempt to ensure the stability of an electrical grid. Grid dynamic response may somewhat change our results. [it is suggested that “somewhat” is an understatement]

Realistically, displaced generators will differ from the generators providing fill-in power and would produce different results.

With respect to the last quote above, there is, or will be, a trend to introduce different types of generator plants (less expensive and more flexible) to balance wind as wind penetration increases. One example would be the increased use of gas turbine (aka GT or SCGT) plants versus combined cycle gas plants (CCGT). The gas turbine plants produce about 50% more emissions per MWh than combined cycle gas plants, the latter being designed to operate in steady state base load or intermediate electricity production roles. This is a major and often overlooked factor that contributes to reducing wind emissions offsets. See additional comments on this in the Questionable Data section in Part II.

Further, the impact of low operating cost of wind plants on wholesale markets, in part due to subsidization, makes more expensive operating cost, but more reliable, generation plant investments less attractive, thus putting at risk long range capacity needs. This is a serious matter for longer term electricity system reliability.

This is not to say that all wind costs are as indicated by wholesale market bidding, which is based only on the cost at the wind plant site, because there are substantial additional electricity systems costs which are incurred solely because of wind’s presence. This is discussed further in Part II.

From the Katzenstein and Apt paper Supporting Information addendum:

Therefore, the results seen in Table 1 of the main paper, obtained from using the full time series of the 5 data sets (see Table S6), estimates only the emission reductions for the conditions that existed during the periods when the data were collected. Ideally, a significant number of high time-resolution independent power plant outputs would be used in our simulations. However we did not have access to such a data set, only to the 5 data sets described. [emphasis added]

The wind data sets were for the relatively short periods of 15, 84, 240 and 370 hours. The fifth data set was for solar PV. This speaks to the limited data impact on conclusive results.

In summary, the Katzenstein and Apt paper does not contribute to robustness for the Cullen paper, due to the limitations of both.

Part I has shown that Cullen’s approach and robustness claims are questionable. Part II will look in more detail at the reliability of the available data, the interstate trade in electricity considerations, and discuss briefly some of Cullen’s acknowledged caveats and some other claims made.


[1] [11] There is an earlier version which may be accessed at http://www.u.arizona.edu/~jcullen/Documents/measuringwind.pdf [12] , but no attempt has been made to confirm that it is an identical document.

[2] [13] EIA http://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/state/ [14] Go to first spreadsheet entitled “Net Generation by State by Type of Producer by Energy Source (EIA-906, EIA-920, and EIA-923)” for Wind data, http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/ [15] Table 10 for Net Interstate Trade and Table 4 for fossil fuel data.

[3] [16] The short term (minutes or less) variation of load and wind in combination produces a greater range of variance than either individually, with a bias towards greater instances of higher variance. An analysis of the Bonneville Power Administration (BPA) in the US northwest electricity production by fuel source at 5 minute intervals shows this. Note that this assumes an arithmetic summation of all wind production, and grid restrictions might exacerbate this experience on a more localized basis.

[4] [17] For information on KEMA, a Netherlands based international consulting firm, start with this [18] and note that DNV acquired 74.3% of KEMA shares. The new company name is DNV KEMA [19].

Where Wind Studies Go Wrong: Cullen in AEJ (Part II)

“The level of emissions savings provided by wind plants has never been conclusively determined, taking into account all the factors.”

Part I yesterday questioned the analysis and robustness of Joseph Cullen’s study, “Measuring the Environmental Benefits of Wind-Generated Electricity” [1]. [1] [20] Part II completes the commentary on this paper, covering:

Questionable Data

The level of emissions savings provided by wind plants has never been conclusively determined, taking into account all the factors. Further, there is no published accurate, minute-by-minute, actual fuel consumption or emissions by individual plant, especially for systems with notable levels of wind present. Note the limitations in the Katzenstein and Apt paper looked to by Cullen for corroboration as discussed in Part I.

In general, government reported emissions are estimates based on calculations using assumptions and relatively simple algorithms. In some cases, actual measurements are taken but are no better than those calculated as reported by the International Energy Agency [21] (see page 35).

Commercial instrumentation is available for monitoring CO2 concentration and flue gas volume flows. Given the limitations of such instrumentation, the accuracy of directly measured CO2 release is probably no better than that derived by indirect calculation. [emphasis added]

A report by The Sustainable Energy Authority in Ireland, “Renewable Energy in Ireland [22]”, in Appendix 1 also refreshingly recognizes the limitations to existing reporting methods.

The assumption underpinning this approach is that the renewable plant is displacing the last plants to be dispatched to meet electricity demand, i.e. the marginal oil and gas plants. There are clear limitations in this analysis but it does provide useful indicative results.” [emphasis added for “indicative”, which is taken to mean “suggestive”]

“The limitations and caveats associated with this methodology include that it ignores any plant used to meet the associated reserve requirements of renewables. These open cycle plants will typically have lower efficiency and generate increased CO2 and NOx emissions compared with CCGT and these emissions should be incorporated into the analysis. The purpose of presenting a simplified analysis here is to provide initial insights into the amount of fossil fuels that are displaced by renewables and the amount of emissions thereby avoided. [emphasis added]

The issue raised in the last quote speaks to the comments made in the Robustness section in Part I.

The above comments point out some of the typical shortcomings of many current approaches in determining reported emissions offsets for wind. At best, such results are useful only as some indication and for rough comparison purposes, for example between jurisdictions and time periods, and not reliable for absolute levels.

The Cullen article admits that the modelling approach used, “relies only on publicly available generator output and characteristics”. Emphasis has been added to the quote because there is no adequate, publicly available information on the constant cycling required of other generation plants mirroring wind plants’ highly random output on a short-term basis, as indicated in Katzenstein and Apt’s paper in Part I.

Cullen somewhat distances his results from the EPA system CEMS on the basis that CEMS reporting includes less than two-thirds of the generators in the ERCOT system, a notable comment in itself.

As a robustness check, I estimate the same model with hourly emissions data from the EPA’s Continuous Emissions Monitoring System (CEMS) as the dependent variable. Using CEMS data may be able to account for the changes in the emissions rate due to efficiency changes, though it may exacerbate ramping effects.

The latter part of this quote needs elaboration. Cullen shows that using the CEMS data in his model results in 4% lower CO2 emissions offsets for wind. He concludes that this indicates relative robustness, but the CEMS data “may” exacerbate ramping effects. This implies that Cullen has in fact captured the ramping effects, which is very questionable as already described.

However, CEMS reporting is subject to question as indicated above. Also note that the CEMS data is hourly based, which likely masks ramping effects on much shorter time intervals in which electricity system balancing must operate to ensure system reliability. In summary the CEMS information more likely understates the ramping effect.

So questionable or incomplete data is a problem in the determination of complete and accurate results, and any corroboration claimed by Cullen is questionable.

Interstate Trade in Electricity

This is a factor that is almost always overlooked in analyses of wind performance, and is not taken fully into account in the modelling here. The general reason for this is that electricity exports to or imports from another jurisdiction are a somewhat complicated matter, and unfortunately often are taken to be relatively inconsequential, which they usually are not.

When Cullen is talking about electricity imports, it is presumed he is talking about net interstate trade, as opposed to import/export of electricity in connection with another country. For simplicity here, the terms “interstate trade” and “exports/imports” will be used to refer to interstate trade only. Further it is important to be clear whether or not any reference to this is a net number of exports/imports as is often the case in reported values.

Cullen also says that he observes the flows of electricity over connection lines in neighboring grids in 15 minute intervals and claims that less than 1 percent of daily generation is exchanged with other grids, while wind accounts for approximately 2%, which allows him to restrict his analysis to within the Texas system. However, this does not agree with EIA reports, [2] [23] as summarized in Table 1.

Table 1 – Wind Production and Net Interstate Trade as Percent of Total Texas Electricity Production.

Note that total wind production is at the same level as net interstate trade for two of the three years that Cullen analyzed, but the net of the interstate trade and could conceal larger amounts of export and import levels over the same period.

Further, Cullen talks in terms of imports, but in the three years analyzed, Texas was a net exporter of electricity. Note the balancing of Supply and Disposition in the reference shown for Table 1. Some clarification of this by Cullen would have been helpful.

In summary, notwithstanding the relative isolation of the Texas electricity system, interstate trade in electricity cannot be ignored in the analysis, and exports/imports even on a net basis could just as easily account for much of the reductions in fossil fuel plant emissions as wind.

To further examine misunderstandings in connection with inter-jurisdiction trade in electricity, in footnote 30 for imports, Cullen suggests that if it was assumed that the emissions offset profile of imports to be the same as in the models, this would change the results found.

It is preferable to assume imports carry no emissions, as it would be very difficult to identify the specific source of the electricity generation profile behind the exported electricity. For the purposes of simplicity in explaining this, assume that such distinction can be made in a couple of simple cases.

Case 1

The exporting jurisdiction is exporting electricity associated with emissions. For the importing jurisdiction to also be charged with these emissions would be double accounting, unless the exporter took a balancing credit. Imagine the complex negotiation associated with this arrangement.

Case 2

In the case of exporting electricity from non-emissions producing generation there is no need to associate emissions with either the export or import as well. However there is an example where this is not done. Denmark reports emissions in two ways: (1) as produced, and (2) after taking credit to reduce its actual emissions based on the amount of exported wind production.

The latter view is often cited in error. See Peeling Away the Onion of Danish Wind [24] for more details. Here as above, this works if the receiving jurisdiction takes a balancing increase in reported emissions, which is unlikely, resulting in a double accounting for emissions reductions, an undesirable outcome.

Admittedly inter-jurisdiction trade in electricity is somewhat complicated, and the above descriptions are simplifications to illustrate the need to view associated emissions as staying within the electricity generating jurisdiction. Imports/exports from and to another jurisdiction should be treated as emissions free.

Perhaps the most important matter is that in most cases, even in Texas, imports and exports of electricity must be fully taken into account when analyzing the emissions impact of wind presence.

Acknowledged Shortcomings

The paper contains appropriate caveats including:

These properly acknowledged limitations reduce the value of the paper in providing useful insights and reliable conclusions about the effects of deployment of wind power.

Questionable Opinions/Claims

There are a number these, which further reduce the value of this paper.

The statement, “In fact, nearly all costs associated with wind power production are incurred during the construction and installation phase of a wind farm.” is not correct. Substantial additional costs are incurred by the presence of wind in (1) otherwise not needed, dispatchable capacity to balance wind’s persistently, erratic behavior within short periods of time (minutes or less) and unreliability on a longer term basis of hours and days, and (2) in substantial increases to the grid unique to wind to gather wind’s dispersed generation, transmit it to typically distant demand centers and support demand management in distribution systems. See the series on “Wind Consequences [25]” for more information.

A modern 1 MW (not 1 MWh) wind turbine does not require only “roughly $1 million” to install. Overnight implementation costs are over twice this amount according to the EIA [26].

Cullen assumes a Wind turbine life of 20 years and that any change in operating efficiency over its lifetime is negligible. This is contrary to experience that shows substantial reductions in performance measured by load factor (aka capacity factor). Figure 2 shows experience in Denmark and the UK. [3] [27]

Figure 2 – Performance Degradation of Wind Turbines in Denmark and the UK

The values shown here are weighted by capacity, because this better captures the effect of the most numerous wind turbine sizes, and produces more typical results than simple averaging. The years with no values are because of little or no experience. Outages due to mechanical failure are included in these statistics.

Most of today’s wind turbine installations have occurred since 2000. These are typically 1-3 MW and much larger than their predecessors. These larger wind turbines have a 100 ton [4] [28] blade assembly and nacelle enclosing the generator on top of a 200 foot, or more, tower. They are reported to be [29] the largest rotating structures in the world. A possible explanation of Denmark’s slower degradation experience may be because most were installed before 2000 and the majority are of a much smaller size.

There are many considerations behind these numbers, but a strong case is made for concern about considerably shorter than generally expected life times for wind turbines, as indicated by the quote from this paper:

With such low levels of performance it seems very unlikely that large wind farms will continue in operation beyond 10 years of age, with a strong likelihood of re-powering at that point. The consequence is that large scale reliance upon wind power seems likely to involve a regular – and costly – commitment to upgrading major components of the wind turbines.

There are other reports on frequent, major component failures requiring substantial costs in the order those for the initial implementation. [5] [30]

On page 112, Cullen refers to a paper by Holland and Mansur [31], which describes how real time retail pricing would shape demand by reducing peaks and shifting load to low cost periods at night. Holland and Mansur explain that this can have an impact on emissions, but whether the impact is positive or negative depends on the generation plant profile of the jurisdiction. Cullen claims that wind plants likewise reshape demand, which is not obvious at all. Apart from the fact that there is no mention by Cullen of the necessary attendant real-time retail pricing, wind usually has higher production at night, and it thus tends to shape low cost production base load generation (not demand) in this period. Further he states that this re-shaping of demand necessarily leads to emissions offsets, which is different from Holland and Mansur’s conclusions which allows for the possibility of increased emissions as well.

As described above in the Analysis Approach section, a major effect of wind is its impact on short term residual demand variances, a totally different type of demand shaping. This shapes the residual demand in a non-beneficial way and arguably increases emissions overall.

Cullen states, “However, for both economic and environmental reasons, hydro facilities are unlikely to spill water over dams without generating electricity.” This is clearly an inappropriate assumption and demonstrates his emphasis on market participants determining electricity system operations. The Bonneville Power Administration (BPA) in the Pacific Northwest provides an instructive case study of system operational issues and associated contortions required here [32] and here [33].

Another related comment by Cullen is, “Both nuclear and aggregate hydropower production will be largely unaffected by the roll out of wind farms.” The use of “largely” is acknowledged, but the statement can be read to suggest non-problematic impacts. The BPA experience above speaks to the hydro aspects. Admittedly nuclear is an unlikely form of electricity generation to be offset by wind, but it does happen as discussed here [34].

A final very questionable claim is, “First, technology advancements in wind turbines have reduced the cost of wind power by 80 percent over the past 30 years (Wiser and Bolinger 2007 [35]).” I could not find confirmation of this claim in the referenced paper. A chart on page 21 does show project costs per kW reducing by about 65% between 1982 to 2000 and then increasing thereafter. This has a related comment in footnote 35, ” Limited sample size early on – particularly in the 1980s – makes it difficult to pin down this number with a high degree of confidence.”

Further to claim technology advancements have been the cause is questionable. The cost per kW of a wind turbine has been largely influenced by simple mechanical considerations, primarily the size of the blades and height of the tower, both of which have increased dramatically over this period.

Summary

Given the very large portion of national wealth (multiples of $trillions [36]) necessary for the contemplated extensive deployment of wind plants, and the associated longer term risks to electricity system viability and reliability, we simply have to do better at complete and conclusive analysis of the impact of wind plants with much improved public availability of operational data on generation plants, including real time fuel consumption and accurate emissions. Fuel consumption may be the only realistic way to assess emissions.

It is questionable that sophisticated econometric modelling is appropriate for this task.


[1] [37] As indicated in Part I, there is an earlier version which may be accessed at http://www.u.arizona.edu/~jcullen/Documents/measuringwind.pdf [12] , but no attempt has been made to confirm that it is an identical document.

[2] [38] EIA (2012). http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/ [39] For interstate trade see table 10. for Wind data, http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/ [15]

[3] [40] Hughes, Gordon (2012). “The Performance of Wind Farms in the United Kingdom and Denmark” http://www.ref.org.uk/attachments/article/280/ref.hughes.19.12.12.pdf [41] Chart is based on calculations from Figure 2.

[4] [42] AWEA http://www.aweo.org/faq.html [43]

[5] [44] This is not widely reported, and some links to sites previously dealing with this topic appear to have removed the documents in question. Here are some currently available reports relating to this matter.

http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2010/06/wind-turbine-gearbox-reliability?cmpid=WindNL-Thursday-June17-2010 [45]

http://billothewisp.blogspot.co.uk/2013/12/wind-turbines-ghost-in-gearbox.html [46]

http://www.queensu.ca/pps/reports/windstudy.pdf [47]

Originally published at Master Resource, February 13 [48] and 14 [49], 2014.


URL to article:  https://www.wind-watch.org/documents/where-wind-studies-go-wrong-cullen-in-aej/


URLs in this post:

[1] “Measuring the Environmental Benefits of Wind-Generated Electricity”: http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/pol.5.4.107

[2] [1]: #_edn1

[3] “the largest and most complex machine ever made.”: http://www.nap.edu/catalog.php?record_id=11735

[4] [2]: #_edn2

[5] [3]: #_edn3

[6] [4]: #_edn4

[7] “Emissions Comparison for a 20 MW Flywheel-based Frequency Regulation Power Plant”: http://www.beaconpower.com/files/KEMA_Report_Emissions_Comparisons_July_%202007.pdf

[8] “Wind turbines increase fossil fuel consumption & CO2 emission”: http://www.clepair.net/windSchiphol.html

[9] “Air Emissions Due to Wind and Solar Power”: http://pubs.acs.org/doi/pdfplus/10.1021/es801437t

[10] Supporting Information: http://pubs.acs.org/doi/suppl/10.1021/es801437t/suppl_file/es801437t_si_001.pdf

[11] [1]: #_ednref1

[12] http://www.u.arizona.edu/~jcullen/Documents/measuringwind.pdf: http://www.u.arizona.edu/~jcullen/Documents/measuringwind.pdf%20

[13] [2]: #_ednref2

[14] http://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/state/: http://www.eia.gov/electricity/data/state/%20

[15] http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/: http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/

[16] [3]: #_ednref3

[17] [4]: #_ednref4

[18] this: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/KEMA

[19] DNV KEMA: http://www.dnvkema.com/about/default.aspx

[20] [1]: #_2edn1

[21] International Energy Agency: http://www.iea.org/ciab/papers/power_generation_from_coal.pdf

[22] Renewable Energy in Ireland: http://www.seai.ie/Publications/Statistics_Publications/Renewable_Energy_in_Ireland/RE_in_Ire_2010update.pdf

[23] [2]: #_2edn2

[24] Peeling Away the Onion of Danish Wind: https://www.wind-watch.org/documents/peeling-away-the-onion-of-denmark-wind/

[25] Wind Consequences: http://www.masterresource.org/2012/09/wind-consequences-i/%20

[26] EIA: http://www.eia.gov/oiaf/beck_plantcosts/pdf/updatedplantcosts.pdf

[27] [3]: #_2edn3

[28] [4]: #_2edn4

[29] reported to be: https://www.asme.org/engineering-topics/articles/renewable-energy/wind-turbines-get-bigger-smarter

[30] [5]: #_2edn5

[31] Holland and Mansur: http://www.nber.org/papers/w13508.pdf?new_window=1

[32] here: http://www.nytimes.com/cwire/2011/02/25/25climatewire-bonneville-power-to-wind-generators-shut-dow-22723.htm

[33] here: http://articles.latimes.com/2011/jun/14/nation/la-na-adv-wind-energy-20110614

[34] here: http://www.masterresource.org/2012/03/ontario-windpower-case-study-ii/

[35] Wiser and Bolinger 2007: http://www.nrel.gov/docs/fy08osti/43025.pdf

[36] multiples of $trillions: http://www.masterresource.org/2012/09/wind-consequences-i/

[37] [1]: #_2ednref1

[38] [2]: #_2ednref2

[39] http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/: http://www.eia.gov/electricity/state/texas/%20

[40] [3]: #_2ednref3

[41] http://www.ref.org.uk/attachments/article/280/ref.hughes.19.12.12.pdf: http://www.ref.org.uk/attachments/article/280/ref.hughes.19.12.12.pdf

[42] [4]: #_2ednref4

[43] http://www.aweo.org/faq.html: http://www.aweo.org/faq.html

[44] [5]: #_2ednref5

[45] http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2010/06/wind-turbine-gearbox-reliability?cmpid=WindNL-Thursday-June17-2010: http://www.renewableenergyworld.com/rea/news/article/2010/06/wind-turbine-gearbox-reliability?cmpid=WindNL-Thursday-June17-2010

[46] http://billothewisp.blogspot.co.uk/2013/12/wind-turbines-ghost-in-gearbox.html: http://billothewisp.blogspot.co.uk/2013/12/wind-turbines-ghost-in-gearbox.html

[47] http://www.queensu.ca/pps/reports/windstudy.pdf: http://www.queensu.ca/pps/reports/windstudy.pdf

[48] February 13: http://www.masterresource.org/2014/02/where-wind-studies-go-wrong-part-i-2/

[49] 14: http://www.masterresource.org/2014/02/where-wind-studies-go-wrong-part-i/